Google Has A Great Business, But Regulatory Risk Is Serious

Summary

  • Google's business advantages are highlighted in the August 5, 2024 Memorandum Opinion court document.
  • Google's superior search engine and advertising system make it a top choice for partnerships like Apple's default search engine deal.
  • Given the ruling against Google with respect to text ads, regulation risk is now a serious concern.

400tmax

Introduction

Per my July article, Google (NASDAQ:GOOG) (NASDAQ:GOOGL) continues performing well as the world embraces AI. Since that time, the August 5, 2024 Memorandum Opinion court document has come out, and it isAAPLMSFT

Development And Investments

Early Google Innovations (Memorandum Opinion court document)

Navboost is another signal that pairs queries and documents through memorizing user click data. It allows Google to remember which documents users clicked after entering a query and to identify when a single document is clicked in response to multiple queries.

Google Innovations (Memorandum Opinion court document)

Scale

Early on, Google understood that the information gleaned from user queries and click activity were a strong proxy for users’ intent and that such information could be used to deliver superior results. (“[M]ost of the knowledge that powers Google, that makes it magical, ORIGINATES in the minds of Google users.”); (“As people interact with the search results page, their actions teach us about the world.”).

There are different types of user data. Click data, for example, includes the search results on which a user clicks; whether the user returns to the SERP and how quickly; how long a user hovers over SERP results; and the user’s scrolling patterns on the SERP. From such data, a GSE learns not only about the user’s interests but also the relevance of the search results and quality of the webpages that the user visits.

Armed with its scale advantage, Google continues to use that data to improve search quality. Google deploys user data to, among other things, crawl additional websites, expand the index, re-rank the SERP, and improve the “freshness” of results (i.e., bring them up to date). Click-and-query data also is used to build and train models that algorithmically improve results’ relevance and ranking, as well as to run large-format experiments to develop new features. Scale also improves search ads monetization.

Google Network Effects (Memorandum Opinion court document)

AI And User Intent

A noncommercial query is one in which the user seeks to retrieve information that the GSE does not attempt to monetize by delivering a search advertisement. 80% of Google’s queries are noncommercial in nature.

The more recent LLM signals did not replace Navboost and QBST in ranking. (“Navboost remains one of the most [powerful] ranking components historically[.]”). Nor did they render the generalization systems obsolete. LLMs are used as “additional signals that get balanced both against each other as well as against other signals[.]”

Importantly, generative AI has not (or at least, not yet) eliminated or materially reduced the need for user data to deliver quality search results. (“[T]he middle problem of figuring out what are the most relevant pages for a given query in a given context still benefits enormously from query click information. And it’s absolutely not the case that AI models eliminate that need or supplant that need.”); ( MUM “definitely” did not replace traditional data-based signals, like Navboost and QBST).

Currently, AI cannot replace the fundamental building blocks of search, including web crawling, indexing, and ranking. Neeva’s experience is again illustrative. Despite building a search engine enhanced by AI technology, Neeva could not ride it to market success. AI may someday fundamentally alter search, but not anytime soon.

Best Search Engine By Far

Google still has the best search engine by far.

Google is the clear winner when it comes to product experience and what users want.

provides customers with the best overall device experience.

It has long been the best search engine, particularly on mobile devices. Nor has Google sat still; it has continued to innovate in search. Google’s partners value its quality, and they continue to select Google as the default because its search engine provides the best bet for monetizing queries. Apple and Mozilla occasionally assess Google’s search quality relative to its rivals and find Google’s to be superior.

Microsoft understood that it “would have to pay and even subsidize the transfer” for the period of transition and was willing to do so for the long term. Microsoft offered Apple a revenue share rate of 90%, or a little under $20 billion over five years. It did so recognizing that “there was going to be a period of turbulence of shift,” both as a result of the change and assuming that Google would respond by encouraging users to abandon Safari for its browser, Chrome. When that offer was not accepted, Microsoft proposed sharing 100% of its Bing revenue with Apple to secure the default or even selling Bing to Apple.

Apple was concerned that despite the high revenue share percentage, Bing would not be able to bring in sufficient revenues because it was “horrible at monetizing advertising.” (“If you have an inferior search engine, customers wouldn’t use it, and so, therefore, I don’t know how you could monetize it well.”).

Otherwise it [was a] no brainer to stay with Google as it is as close to a sure thing as can be. (And so Google’s a sure thing. They have the best search engine, they know how to advertise, and they’re monetizing really well.).

According to Cue, there was “no price that Microsoft could ever offer [Apple]” to make the switch, because of Bing’s inferior quality and the associated business risk of making a change. (“I don’t believe there’s a price in the world that Microsoft could offer us. They offered to give us Bing for free. They could give us the whole company.”).

US search access points (Author’s spreadsheet based on the Memorandum Opinion court document)

Regulatory Risk

Ultimately, the court concludes that Google’s exclusive distribution agreements have contributed to Google’s maintenance of its monopoly power in two relevant markets: general search services and general search text advertising.

Plaintiffs collectively assert that Google has monopoly power in three overlapping advertising markets. These markets and their relationships are illustrated below. U.S. Plaintiffs allege the broadest proposed market, search advertising, which includes all advertisements served in response to a query, regardless of the digital platform. Within the search ads market, Plaintiff States define a general search advertising market that includes only ads served on GSEs. Finally, both sets of Plaintiffs propose a general search text advertising market, limited to text ads appearing on a GSE’s SERP.

Overlapping ad markets (Memorandum Opinion court document)

Amazon’s US ads business is nearly the size of Google’s US retail ads business today, and is growing at over twice Google’s rate.

The court has found that Plaintiffs have proven that Google has monopoly power in two relevant product markets: general search services and general search text advertising. On the other hand, although the court recognized a separate market for search ads, it found that Google did not have monopoly power in that market. It also rejected a separate general search ads market.

The bulk of Plaintiffs’ case focuses on the search distribution contracts - the browser agreements (primarily with Apple and Mozilla) and the Android agreements (the MADAs and RSAs) - which Google allegedly uses to maintain its monopoly in the relevant markets.

The key question then is this: Do Google’s exclusive distribution contracts reasonably appear capable of significantly contributing to maintaining Google’s monopoly power in the general search services market? The answer is “yes.” Google’s distribution agreements are exclusionary contracts that violate Section 2 because they ensure that half of all GSE users in the United States will receive Google as the preloaded default on all Apple and Android devices, as well as cause additional anticompetitive harm. The agreements “clearly have a significant effect in preserving [Google’s] monopoly.”

The agreements have three primary anticompetitive effects: (1) market foreclosure, (2) preventing rivals from achieving scale, and (3) diminishing the incentives of rivals to invest and innovate in general search. Plaintiffs also contend that Google’s incentives to invest are diminished, but the evidence of that effect is weaker than the others.

Google has not met its burden to establish that valid procompetitive benefits explain the need for exclusive default distribution. Accordingly, Plaintiffs have established that Google is liable under Section 2 of the Sherman Act for unlawfully maintaining its monopoly in the market for general search services through its exclusive distribution agreements with browser developers and Android OEMs and carriers.

The company said that the government should ban the agreements that made Google’s search engine the default option on devices, give others access to Google’s search and ads knowledge, present screens that allow people to change search engines easily and educate the public about the process of picking a new search engine.

Valuation

Disclaimer: Investing carries risk. This is not financial advice. The above content should not be regarded as an offer, recommendation, or solicitation on acquiring or disposing of any financial products, any associated discussions, comments, or posts by author or other users should not be considered as such either. It is solely for general information purpose only, which does not consider your own investment objectives, financial situations or needs. TTM assumes no responsibility or warranty for the accuracy and completeness of the information, investors should do their own research and may seek professional advice before investing.

Report

Comment

  • Top
  • Latest
empty
No comments yet